Tag: goldprice

  • Rabobank: “Gold is a bubble which will burst”

    Gold is a bubble which will burst, according to Rabobank chief investment officer Han Dieperink. In his latest update on financial markets, he expects gold to drop below $500 per troy ounce, much lower than the current price of about $1.315 per troy ounce. He sees a pattern in the price of gold which resembles a bubble that is about to burst, presented in the graph below. Apparently, he doesn’t take into consideration the lowest interest rates ever recorded in human history and the fact that central banks are adding gold to their reserves.

    goud-zeepbelAccording to Dieperink, the inflation-adjusted price of gold has been around $400 per troy ounce for the last hundred years. From his perspective, the rise of gold to $1.900 per troy ounce back in 2011 was clearly a bubble. Based on his bubble theory, he expects the gold price to fall by as much as 70% to a level below $500 per troy ounce. The Rabobank analyst made a similar forecast in late 2015. Since then, the price of gold rose from a multi-year bottom of $1.060 all the way to $1.370 per troy ounce.

    Rabobank still negative on gold

    While analysts from ABN Amro, JP Morgan and Credit Suisse revised their gold forecast to a new reality of lower rates and more quantitative easing, the Rabobank sticks to the $500 scenario. Dieperink points to the negative interest rates, the Brexit referendum and fear in the financial markets to explain the rising price of gold since the beginning of this year. But apparently, he doesn’t expect those fundamentals to have a long-lasting impact on the price of the precious metal.

    rabobank

    Rabobank expects gold to drop to less than $500 per troy ounce

    Gold is not a commodity

    According to Dieperink, there is no reason why the price of gold can’t drop below the cost of production (about $850 per troy ounce), because there is a huge above ground supply of gold in the market. This is a weakness in his reasoning, because the value of gold is not determined only by it’s use as a commodity. If that would be the case, the metal would have been worthless already, since there has been a substantial supply of above ground gold for centuries. The stock to flow ratio of gold will gradually increase over time, due to large scale gold mining.

    For central banks and a large part of the world population, gold is more a wealth reserve than a commodity. The use of gold in industry is limited, because there are often cheaper alternatives around. Instead, most of the gold is held by individuals and centrale banks in the form of jewelry, coins and bars. In other words, as an alternative store of value and as a wealth reserve. The price of gold doesn’t go to zero, because the metal is being hoarded by savers and investors around the world.

    In an environment of negative rates and with growing distrust towards central banks and governments, more people favor physical gold over paper financial assets. Russia, China and other central banks are not buying gold to make a buck from a new bull market in gold. No, they buy it as a tangible wealth reserve besides foreign exchange reserves.

    Flight to safety

    The wealthy are looking for a safe haven and the number of options is shrinking rapidly. When you think gold is a bubble, you might want to call government bonds a bubble as well. What is the purpose of buying a government bond, if the expected cashflow is zero or even negative.

  • ABN Amro revised gold price forecast to $1.300

    The ABN Amro revised their gold price forecast for 2016 from $900 to $1.300 per troy ounce. The upward revision is remarkable, because the bank held a negative stance towards gold for the past couple of years. As recently as December last year, precious metals analyst Georgette Boele was still convinced the gold price would find a bottom at around $900 during 2016. In her forecast for this year, she wrote about the downward pressure on gold because of the expectation of more rate hikes by the Federal Reserve.

    abn-amro-logoBoele explained she was caught by surprise by the sudden turmoil in the financial markets, which painted a bleak picture for the state of the world economy in both the United States and in the emerging markets around the world. Boele is expecting more trouble ahead for those countries relying on the export of commodities.

    Interest rates

    She also revised her expectations regarding the Federal Reserve monetary policy. The probability of a rate increase by the Federal Reserve diminished substantially because of the downturn in the stock market and the sudden move to safe havens like precious metals. With higher interest rates, buying gold becomes less attractive, because the yellow metal doesn’t yield any interest or dividends.

    Expectations of rising interest rates drove the price of gold down to the lowest level in more than five years, but now the outlook has changed. Falling share prices and the exceptionally low price of oil suggest that the global economy is growing at a much slower pace. As a result, banking stocks are under even more pressure, losing 20% on average since the start of 2016.

    Gold price moving up

    The price of gold has risen more than 15% this year, a strong rally making it the best performing commodity of 2016 so far. The sudden price increase from the lowest level in five years caught analyst Boele by surprise. In an explanation for Bloomberg she said: “Having been long-standing bears we have now turned bullish on precious metal prices. Our new scenario sees a longer period of weaker global growth.”

    She also revised her 2016 forecast for other precious metals. From $15,00 to $16,50 per troy ounce for silver and from $900 to $1.050 for one troy ounce of platinum.

    oude-koersdoel-abn-amro

    ABN Amro was expecting $900 gold in 2016 just a few months ago

    gs-logo-breed

    This article is provided by Goudstandaard.com

  • Move over ZIRP… Here Comes NIRP!

    Precious metals prices enter the new week looking to extend the rally that began Oct. 2nd. Silver has gained nearly 10%, and gold is up almost 3.5%. The notion that the Federal Reserve governors may have missed their window to raise interest rates is beginning to sink in with investors. In fact, if the U.S. economy should fall into recession, investors may see central planners move from zero interest rate policy (ZIRP) to the launch of negative interest rates.

    negative-interest-ratesThe minutes from the most recent Federal Open Market Committee meeting reveal Janet Yellen and company are looking to the socialists in Europe for ideas, and central bankers there have already experimented with negative interest rate policy (NIRP).

    Bottom line: You should soon expect to start paying interest for the “privilege” of lending your savings to a bank!

    This week, investors will be watching reports on inflation, retail sales, and industrial production. The prospect of recession continues to loom larger, despite a small rally in stock prices. For now, investors seem more focused on the delay in hiking interest rates than deteriorating fundamentals.

    Precious Metals: More Important Than Ever in Your Portfolio

    Nobody is talking about it these days, but we still live in an inflationary age. Wall Street is fixated on the possibility of deflation as prices for crude oil fall and headline Consumer Price Index flat-lines. But the wheels of global inflation continue to turn. Zero interest rates and bond purchasing programs have defined central bank policy for most of the last decade. Central bankers developed these extraordinary programs and sold them to the public as economic stimulus. It is now clear just how little of that largesse made its way into the real economy. We now know the real purpose of those programs was to stimulate bank profits and boost equity markets. Meanwhile, government debt and entitlement commitments have only grown larger. That epic problem was top of mind for investors when gold and silver spot prices peaked in 2011. Battles over the debt ceiling and inflation fears captured headlines. inflation-dollarUnfortunately for precious metals bulls, the central planners at the Fed and Wall Street managed to shift investor focus away from those topics. Higher stock prices, heavily massaged economic data on employment and consumer prices, and hammering down of paper gold and silver prices all help to mask the fundamental problems that make metals so essential in modern portfolios. These days, most investors seem unconcerned about the inflationary potential of the trillions of dollars created by the Federal Reserve to buy U.S. Treasury bonds and mortgage securities. Many are outright “inflation deniers,” and few seem the least bit worried about what ZIRP or NIRP will ultimately do to the purchasing power of the dollar. But rewarding borrowers and spenders while waging jihad against savers IS going to lead to serious ramifications. And all those extra dollars created in multiple rounds of QE are out there – in the stock markets, parked as excess bank reserves, and just about everywhere else but in the real economy. Inflation and financial sector risks have not been vanquished. They are still there, and, in fact, they are still growing. They aren’t weighing heavily in investor psychology today, but change is already in the air. Fear will factor prominently in investor decision making once again – perhaps soon. The Federal Reserve is in no position to significantly raise interest rates. Congressional Republicans will soon reveal just how incapable they are of drawing a line in the sand on raising the federal debt ceiling even higher than the current $18.1 trillion cap. And people are once again talking about the possibility of recession. Investors are starting to worry about exorbitant price to earnings (P/E) valuations, falling corporate profits, and a potential bond bubble. Some corporate and municipal bonds are priced as if the borrower was Apple when the financial statements look more like they belong to Enron. Despite all of the disparaging talk about precious metals, there is always demand for an inflation hedge that offers privacy, diversification, and zero risk of going bankrupt. Look for investor demand to rise dramatically in the coming years in spite of the bias against gold from Wall Street. Gold and silver may be down, but after thousands of years of history as a reliable store of value, but they are anything but out. clint-siegner

    Money Metals Exchange

    Clint Siegner is a Director at Money Metals Exchange, the national precious metals company named 2015 "Dealer of the Year" in the United States by an independent global ratings group. A graduate of Linfield College in Oregon, Siegner puts his experience in business management along with his passion for personal liberty, limited government, and honest money into the development of Money Metals' brand and reach. This includes writing extensively on the bullion markets and their intersection with policy and world affairs.

  • So Who is Still Long in Gold?

    This article is from Armstrong Economics

    As you move into a major low, it is not about who is still long, it is who is short. As gold capitulates and spirals lower, the gold promoters are running out of nonsense to justify it rising while the world is declining. What happens is two aspects. Those who have been long lose their shirt, pants, house, wife, kids, the car, and the dog. The buy-every-dip-average-in advice becomes toxic, just as it did during the Great Depression in stocks – hold now for new highs by year-end is always the prediction. So yes, the investors married to the trade typically lose everything and when the cycle changes, they likely will not buy again unless new highs come into play for they will say, “No thanks, been there done that.” Any rational person can analyze the sales-pitch about fiat and hyperinflation and see that they existed for 19 years as gold declined. Such fundamental analysis scenarios always crumble to dust and fall to the ground for they are never true to the history of events.

    russia-kazakhstan-goldAt the top, the majority is long and they become the fuel to make any market crash and burn. Shorts and conspiracies do not force markets to decline; it is always the LONGS themselves. Someone whom is long sells because he cannot hold and each has a different pain threshold. The market crashes for there is no bid. It takes courage to try to catch a falling knife. Again, this applies to ALL markets. At the bottom, the opposite unfolds for everyone will be short. They will pile on looking for $600 gold and will count their profits upon entering the trade. They become the fuel to send the market higher for it always begins with a short-cover rally; people continually try to sell each rally, looking for that new low, just as the people at the top remain convinced that a decline would follow with new highs. So yes, the majority must always be wrong. That is how highs and lows are established. Going into the low, the vast majority of analysts will flip to bearish. Even the gold promoters will fade for nobody will listen to them again. Look, in 2011 when we warned gold would crash to under $1,000, every name in the book was hurled at us. Gold promoters refused to interview us or report the forecast. Many spent hours trying to say that they were right and we would be dead wrong. It was always cast as a war against fiat. Every excuse from no gold in Fort Knox, to market manipulation by banks, to China would be a real market and make its currency backed by gold as Shanghai destroyed paper gold. The scenarios were endless, but never realistic. Not one stitch of proof exists to point to such a scenario ever taking place in history. Yet they seriously hurt the market and ruined the financial future of many innocent people who trusted them. ONLY when the majority becomes bearish at the low do we reach that sweet spot, and it becomes time for a reversal of fortune. Then on the initial rally out of the ashes, nobody will believe it. Just look at Barron’s and how they reported our forecast back in 2011, stating that the stock market would make new highs. They did not believe that we would be correct because the majority was looking for new lows. When we predicted that the stock market would exceed the 2007 high, many laughed at us, just as they did when we predicted that the gold crash would unfold for 3 to 5 years.

    goldprice-15-years

    Goldprice over the last 15 years

    Source: Armstrongeconomics

  • Banks cannot forecast gold prices

    Based on a short analysis of bank forecasts, we can conclude they are clueless about the direction of the goldprice. Last year we already gathered some forecasts by a number of big commercial banks and now we’ve added the most recent forecasts for 2014. Early 2013, when the gold price was about $1.650 per troy ounce, almost all banks expected prices would rise to $1.800 or even more dollars per troy ounce. Deutsche Bank and Merrill Lynch even expected the price would reach or surpass $2.000 per troy ounce in 2013. The lowest forecast was still $1.650 per troy ounce, so basically none of these banks expected the drop in price we saw last year.

    Gold price forecasts by ten different banks through time

    Gold price forecasts by ten different banks through time

    Bank analysts extrapolate past gold returns?

    After the violent price drop of gold in the first half of 2013, many banks slashed their forecasts for both 2013 and 2014. The red and green bars in the graph show the sudden adjustment to the new reality. Compared to just one year ago, banks slashed their forecasts by hundreds of dollars. For 2014, these banks expect a further price drop to on average $1.187 per troy ounce. That's as low as the 2013 bottom!

    Contrary to what most banks expected, the yellow metal made a nice rebound in early 2014. This year, the price of gold has already gained more than 10% and surpassed the 200 day moving average. This year, the difference between the average gold price and the predicted gold price for 2014 is already $75 per troy ounce, as you can see from the chart below. It seems like bank analysts tend to extrapolate past returns. They were too optimistic in early 2013 and they seem to be too pessimistic on gold right now.

    Difference between gold forecast and the actual gold price

    Difference between gold forecast and the actual gold price

  • Goldprice in six different currencies

    Reuters published an article lately about oil prices in six different emerging market currencies. The graph embedded in this article shows how oil prices are setting new all-time highs in Brazilian reals, Russian rubles, South-African rands and India rupees. Because of the decline of emerging market currencies, people in those countries pay record high prices for a barrel of oil. But what about the goldprice?

    Goldprice in foreign currencies

    The graphs by Reuters inspired us to do the same with gold, which set a new all-time high in dollars in 2011. The goldprice peaked at about $1.920 per troy ounce and has declined ever since. Right now, the price of gold in dollars is about 34% below the all-time high. But what about the price of gold in beaten down emerging market currencies? Marketupdate collected some data and made the following graphs. Most of the data is from the weekly updated spreadsheet published by the World Gold Council, while some data is based on historic exchange rates on the forex market. The graphs start at the 9th of September 2011 and ends with the gold price at the end of January 2014.

    Goldprice in six emerging market currencies since Sept 2011

    Goldprice in six emerging market currencies since Sept 2011

    As you can see the price of gold in some emerging market currencies didn't drop nearly as much as the goldprice in dollars or euros. In South-African rand, the goldprice was actually higher last week than it was in September 2011 (when the goldprice in dollars peaked at $1920 per troy ounce). When measured in Brazilian real, the gold price at the end of January 2014 was only 4,15% below the level of September 2011. For the Turkish lira and the Indian rupee, the gold price went down only 10,3 and 15,5% respectively, much less than the 34% price decline in US dollars over the same period.

    Gold as a hedge

    Gold is above all a hedge against a decline in the local currency. No matter how much governments and the central banks abuse their fiat currencies, they can not influence gold. That's why they don't like you to buy gold. The precious metal is a hedge against their fiat currency system, which is only good as medium of exchange and unit of account. The store of value lies in physical things, gold being the most liquid and uniform one of them.

  • Goldprice in Argentina: +28% in January

    In Argentina, the price of gold rose about 28% in the first month of this year. In the meantime, the price of gold in euro’s and dollars rose about 5%. The big difference is the result of a devaluation of the Argentine currency, the peso. The devaluation is unfortunate for savers, because they saw the real value of their savings decline. The gains are for the debtors, whose debts in real terms went down by the same amount.

    Argentinians who converted their savings into gold were barely harmed by the devaluation of the currency. While the money in their pocket lost some value, their gold didn’t. The price of gold in Argentina rose to such an extent that the holders of physical gold kept the value of their savings. On the first of January, the price of gold was 7.860 Argentine pesos. On the 30th of January, the price was 10.104 pesos. One day before, on the 29th, the goldprice was just 8.981 peso. So in just one day, the goldprice rose by more than 10%!

    The graph below shows the goldprice in six different currencies: the Russian ruble, the Argentine peso, the Turkish lira, the eur, the Indian rupee and the Sout-African rand. As you can see most of the emerging market currencies lost value compared to both the euro and gold.

    Goldprice in five emerging market currencies

    Goldprice in five emerging market currencies (Source: Goudstandaard.com)

    Gold as a hedge against devaluation

    Gold is often cited as a good hedge against inflation, but it would be more accurate to state that gold is a hedge against a devaluation. Sudden drops in the value of a currency are a nightmare for savers, but not for those owning physical gold. Gold stores value in an environment with currency devaluation, while the relationship between gold prices and inflation is not so clear. Last year, Venezuela devalued their bolivar by 44% against the dollar. Those holding the currency lost purchasing power in dollars, but the gold would still buy them the same amount of dollars as the day before the devaluation. Up until now, currency crises are related to banana republics and third world countries. That's why people living in those countries value gold differently than in Western economies, where the precious metal is just an investment opportunity. Gold as a speculative hedge when the stock market goes down, which has to be sold as soon as the stock market picks up again. We beg to differ...

  • Gold premiums in India rise to a record 20%

    While the goldprice on the world spot market is moving sideways, the price of gold in India is rapidly moving higher. The precious metal is in short supply, causing an upward pressure on the price of gold. To get your hands on some physical gold in India, you have to pay a premium of more than 20% nowadays. That’s twice the import duty of 10% on gold bars. Under normal circumstances the premiums on gold are very close to the import duty, as you can see from the graph below.

    In August, the import duty on gold bars was raised from 8% to 10%. But since October gold premiums started to rise rapidly beyond that percentage. The following chart from Chartsrus shows the movement in the Indian gold market.

    Gold close to record high in India

    The rising premiums and a weak rupee combined drive gold prices in India to record high levels. The yellow line in the graph below represents the gold price on the Indian gold market. Notice the difference between this yellow line and the blue line, which represents the gold price in dollars, converted to rupees. The difference is what we see on the red line in the bottom graph and is the margin Indian buyers pay at the jewelry store or to gold traders.

    ‘War on Gold’

    India is still waging a War on Gold, because gold shows the weakness in the currency. Massive imports of gold result in a substantial current account deficit, putting downward pressure on the value of the Indian rupee. The Indian government and central bank try to discourage people from buying gold by increasing import duties, restricting the maximum import quantities and banning the import of gold coins altogether.

    Gold premiums in India rise to a record 20%

    Gold premiums in India rise to a record 20% (Source: Goldchartsrus.com)

  • Gold and the monetary system: The potential US-EU conflict

    Recently Marketupdate published (Dutch) a historical document about the European revaluation of gold reserves. In this article, we write about a conversation between Henry Kissinger and his advisors. Despite the depth of this article we were able to reach quite a substantial audience.

    A lot of time is involved in translating such articles from English to Dutch, but for our English speaking audience we can just copy and paste such documents and provide a brief introduction! 😀

    In the article below you read about the divergence arising between the United States and Europa during the seventies regarding the role of gold in the monetary system. To give a historical perspective on the situation: back in 1974 the US dollar was disconnected from gold, the goldprice was rising fast beyond the official $42,22 per troy ounce and inflation was on the rise. The oil producing countries wanted a better compensation for their oil, now the dollar was no longer backed by a promise to deliver physical gold. As a result, the price of oil started to increase as well, pushing consumer prices higher in both the US and Europe.

    The US wanted to remove the discipline of physical gold OUT of the monetary system, while they received news from Europe about plans to bring gold back IN the monetary system at a higher free market price. This way, gold could be used in international settlements among European countries. Especially Italy and France, countries with both a large deficit and a large part of their reserves in gold, wanted to return to a system in which they could activate their gold reserve to settle debts with other European countries. But they were reluctant to do so, because of the artificially suppressed price of gold of just $42,22 per troy ounce.

    A revaluation of gold was necessary for the European plan to work, but that would be against the interests of the United States. In the following article we can read how the United States analyzed this interesting situation. We have highlighted important parts of this document in green, while the most essential ones are green and bold.

    Please share this article if you liked it!

    ~~~~

    Gold and the monetary system: The potential US-EU conflict

    Washington, May 6th 1974

    This is a paper which we prepared for Secretary Kissinger giving some of our views on the gold question. We discussed it at a meeting for his background,2 without attempting to reach any conclusions. We would appreciate any reactions you have to the paper. The Secretary said he would most appreciate meeting with you and anybody else you wish to designate in about two weeks to talk out the issue and what might be done, using a revised options paper for this purpose. One option that is not included in the paper, but which should be for various reasons, is how to deal with thwarting the Europeans if they were to go ahead without us in a way which we felt was inimical to our interests.

    The Foreign Policy Context

    Within the next few months the long-standing U.S.-European dispute on the role of gold will probably be propelled from the back room to the main stage of our relationship. The stakes in this dispute are high, involving the long-run stability of the international monetary system and prospects for increased dissension within Europe and between Europe and the U.S.

    The Problem

    U.S. objectives for the world monetary system—a durable, stable system, with the SDR as a strong reserve asset at its center—are incompatible with a continued important role for gold as a reserve asset. These objectives are in apparent conflict with the EC desire to facilitate the use of gold in international transactions. There is a belief among certain Europeans that a higher price of gold for settlement purposes would facilitate financing of oil imports, although the argument depends on assumptions regarding producers’ attitude towards gold as an asset which may not be valid. Adamant U.S. insistence on maintaining the present fixed official price is likely to create international conflict with the EC, and may also lead to unilateral EC arrangements which would defeat our aims for the system.

    The Conclusion

    The U.S. objectives are important, and should not be given up, but they may be achievable without rigid adherence to the present fixed official gold price. Compromise proposals exist which would make adequate progress towards our objectives for the system while meeting principal EC needs. Since the EC is likely to set forth its proposals before the C–20 winds up its existence this summer, a U.S. position will be needed within the next several months. Tactically, it may also be preferable to discuss possible compromise proposals with one or more EC members before we are confronted with an EC position.

    Pressures are building within the EC for settlement of intra-EC balances with gold valued at the market price (or some other price substantially higher than the current official price of $42.20 per troy ounce). Unilateral EC action in this direction would run directly counter to the stated United States position on international gold policy. The EC reportedly will try to avoid a direct conflict through pressing for rapid resolution of the problem within the framework of the multilateral monetary reform negotiations. Therefore, the U.S. position needs to be re-examined in light of present circumstances. This memorandum examines the foundations of this potential U.S.–EC conflict on the gold question, and considers which negotiating positions among various options would best serve U.S. interests.

    Gold in the International Monetary System—The Issues

    Agreement has been reached in the C–20 monetary reform negotiations that the SDR should take the place once held by gold at the center of the world monetary system. However, there is still substantial disagreement on what the exact future role of gold should be—whether it eventually ought to be phased out of the system (the U.S. view) or retain an important function as a reserve asset and means of international settlement (the position of some European countries).

    U.S. interests in this question are in the establishment of stable, durable world monetary system, based on a strong SDR, which would avoid future monetary crises and conflict, such as those that have plagued the Bretton Woods system in recent years. In our view a system which included gold as a major reserve asset alongside SDRs would be inherently unstable, just as bimetallism was in the U.S.

    This inherent instability stems from the fact that gold is traded as a commodity on a private market at a variable price subject to the vagaries of world production (largely Soviet and South African) and sales, and of demands by hoarders and speculators. With a fluctuating, and generally rising, free market for gold, a permanently fixed official price is simply not credible, and becomes less so as the gap between private and official prices widens. If, however, the price at which official transactions in gold are made were to be periodically adjusted to the market price, then an unstable situation would rise as between gold and SDRs.

    At the present time, the value of the SDR is fixed in terms of gold. However, it has been generally agreed in the C–20 that the new SDR should not be related to gold, but rather to a basket of currencies. In this case, a changing price at which official gold transactions take place would create capital gains (or losses) for gold holders as compared to SDR holders, stimulate speculative central bank demand for gold, and weaken the SDR.4

    Gold versus the SDR

    It is the U.S. concern that any substantial increase now in the price at which official gold transactions are made would strengthen the position of gold in the system, and cripple the SDR. If international liquidity were injected via gold, there would be little likelihood of new SDR allocations.5 There also would be reduced incentive to sell gold on the private market even after an official price increase since central banks would cling to their gold in expectation of further official gold price increases. In addition, too large an increase in world liquidity might add to inflationary dangers. Finally, the distribution of the increase in world reserves would be highly inequitable, with eight wealthy countries getting three-fourths, while the developing countries would get less than 10 percent (see attached table). Producing countries (the USSR and South Africa) would benefit from the implicit floor put under the free-market gold price.

    To encourage and facilitate the eventual demonetization of gold, our position is to keep the present gold price, maintain the present Bretton Woods agreement ban against official gold purchases at above the official price6 and encourage the gradual disposition of monetary gold through sales in the private market. An alternative route to demonetization could involve a substitution of SDRs for gold with the IMF, with the latter selling the gold gradually on the private market, and allocating the profits on such sales either to the original gold holders, or by other agreement.

    European views on the role of gold in the world monetary system vary considerably. The British and Germans, on one hand, generally agree in principle to the desirability of phasing gold out of the system. On the other end of the spectrum, the French have been the main proponents of a continued important role for gold in the system.

    Support for a continued role for gold in the system is based in large part on the belief that “paper gold”—the SDR—does not command sufficient confidence and acceptability to replace gold completely in the system. There is, in fact, still a considerable emotional attachment to gold as a monetary asset, and a basic distrust of bank or paper money not having intrinsic value.

    On the other hand, most European officials recognize the basic problems involved in a combined SDR–gold reserve asset system. Belgian Finance Minister De Clerq,7 for example, speaking at the IMF annual meetings in September stated:

    Any redefinition of the role of gold must be based on the principle stated above: that SDR must become the center of the system and that there can be no question of introducing a new form of gold– paper and gold–metal bimetallism, in which the SDR and gold would be in competition.

    Immobility of gold

    Despite these differences among member countries, the EC position has begun to coalesce around their desire to free gold for use in settling intra-EC debts—a problem raised by the present “immobilization” of gold which has resulted from the wide disparity between the official and free market gold prices. Monetary authorities have been unwilling to use their gold holdings to settle official debts at a price far below the free market price. This has been a problem particularly for the EC, whose rules under the “snake” arrangement require that final settlement of debts arising out of intervention to support intra-EC exchange rates must be made in reserve assets in proportion to the composition of reserve holdings. (This “immobility” is, of course, an example of the difficulties inherent in a system in which gold retains a reserve currency role alongside another reserve asset.)

    To some extent, the immobility of gold reserves as a means of payment is a result of self-imposed restraints. Countries are free to use reserve currencies and SDRs to settle debts. Moreover, countries are now free to obtain additional currencies (and realize substantial capital gains) through sales of gold to the private market. The EC problem is a result of their particular rules for settlement, which reflect the interest of creditor countries in receiving gold and applying discipline to deficit countries. It is also a result of their reluctance, so far, to sell gold on the private market. The reasons for this reluctance are probably related to the unsettled status of gold in the system, the basic attraction of gold, the expectation of future price increases, and the “thinness” of the private gold market.

    Nor is it clear that European countries would give up gold even after a price increase, since one increase may lead to an expectation of further increases. Even under the Bretton Woods system, the Europeans did not often give up gold to settle deficits.

    The “immobility” problem is of particular concern to the French and Italians, who have substantial outstanding EC debts and especially high proportions of their reserve assets in gold. Recently, with the private price continuing to rise, and final decisions on monetary reform apparently further off than previously thought, other EC countries are coming around to the French-Italian view that this problem must be resolved. However, the Germans and British, in particular, are concerned that the solution be accomplished in a way which would not antagonize the United States. They wish to settle this issue in the C–20 multilateral context, if possible. Failing agreement there, the EC might feel free to unilaterally make some regional arrangement.

    Various European proposals have been made to deal with the gold issue. The basic French proposal in the C–20 was simply to increase the official price of gold although this may have been made with tongue in cheek and received no support other than from South Africa. Other European proposals, and the stated French fallback position, have been variations on the idea that the official price of gold be abolished, leaving the SDR as the sole numeraire of the system, and that monetary authorities be free to deal at a negotiated price, or at a price related (perhaps at a discount) to the private market price. In the version reportedly recently proposed to the EC by the UK, such an arrangement would be combined with coordinated central bank sales to the private market. Another possibility reportedly being considered is to have the Italians, who have the greatest need, sell gold on the private market by themselves to avoid unduly depressing the market. The French version of this proposal would allow central banks either to buy or sell gold on the private market (obviously in order to avoid depressing the private market and to keep or augment the role of gold in the system).

    In lieu of a general agreement permitting official transactions in gold at a price higher than the official price, some EC countries have proposed special arrangements to deal only with the intra-EC problem. Such proposals have heretofore been shelved by a combination of technical problems, and an unwillingness to take unilateral action of doubtful legality and offensive to the United States. Most recently, the EC Commission has proposed a system which would in effect set a higher provisional price, to be corrected when agreement is reached on a new price for gold.

    Both the European C–20 proposal and the intra-EC proposals would fall short of a generalized increase in the official price of gold. However, each would amount to a generalized de facto, if not de jure,8 official price increase, and strengthen the role of gold in the system. A system of sales, but no purchases, to the private market would mitigate this tendency.

    Gold for Oil

    The recent oil price increases have added a new dimension to the gold issue, and in the view of some European officials, relegated the intra-EC problem to a secondary position. Although mobilization of gold for intra-EC settlement would help in the financing of imbalances among EC countries, it would not, of itself, provide resources for the financing of the anticipated deficit with the oil producers. For this purpose, it would be useful if the oil producers would invest some of their excess revenues in gold purchases from deficit EC countries at close to a market price. This would be an attractive proposal for European countries, and for the U.S., in that it would not involve future interest burdens and would avoid immediate problems arising from increased Arab ownership of European and American industry. (The Arabs could both sell the gold and use the proceeds for direct investment, so that the industry ownership problem would not be completely solved.)

    From the Arab point of view such an asset would have the advantages of being protected from exchange-rate changes and inflation, and subject to absolute national control. Some European officials are thinking in terms of clearing the way for such transactions (which would now be forbidden by IMF rules). It has been argued that Arabs would only be interested in buying gold at near the market price if they could obtain assurances of some sort of floor price. We have received word that such a proposal is being floated within the German Government.

    From the standpoint of international liquidity needs, a reasonable case can now be made for a generalized gold price increase, since the probable payments patterns stemming from the higher oil prices (overall deficits for Europe and Japan) may lead to a reduction in world reserve liquidity. However, from the U.S. viewpoint (as well as many countries without large gold holdings) substantial new SDR allocations would be preferable when new liquidity creation is needed.

    Options for U.S. Negotiating Policy on Gold

    Since the U.S. is likely to be presented with pressure to acquiesce in some arrangements to meet the European objectives sketched out above, it is important that we reconsider what our own negotiating posture should be.

    At either end of the spectrum of possible negotiating positions are the following:

    Option 1: Continue adamant opposition to any proposal involving an increase in price at which monetary authorities carry out transactions in gold.

    Advantages: If successful, we will keep gold from regaining strength as an international reserve asset, maintain the strength of the SDR, and probably eventually obtain the demonetization of gold and a more rational, stable international monetary system.

    Disadvantages: The EC may then go ahead with its own arrangements which would amount to a virtual de facto increase in the official gold price, with undesirable effects on the world monetary system and lead to increased U.S.–EC conflict and bitterness.

    Option 2: Acquiesce in a European-type plan involving abolition of the official price, permitting settlement of official balances at a negotiated price, with a “sales only” rule for transactions in the private market.

    Advantages: This would be somewhat preferable to a plan involving an outright increase in the official price, and would maintain an avenue for demonetization through one-way sales to the private market. The SDR would become the sole numeraire of the system. In the short run, tensions with Europe over monetary issues would be reduced. The increase in de facto liquidity might be helpful in present circumstances, and gold sales to the Arabs might help finance western balance of payments deficits.

    Disadvantages: This has most of the disadvantages discussed above of (and may in fact lead to) an outright increase in the official price of gold. We may thereby lose the opportunity to build a stable and rational world monetary system, with adverse long-term consequences involving monetary instability and conflict.

    The disadvantages to each of these options are such that a search for additional options is justified. Intermediate options do exist which have the potential of meeting EC objectives of mobilizing gold in the short run, while maintaining the desirable trend towards gold demonetization.

    Option 3: Complete short-term demonetization of gold through an IMF substitution facility. Countries could give up their gold holdings to the IMF in exchange for SDRs. The gold could then be sold gradually, over time, by the IMF to the private market. Profits from the gold sales could be distributed in part to the original holders of the gold, allowing them to realize at least part of the capital gains, while part of the profits could be utilized for other purposes, such as aid to LDCs.

    Advantages: This would achieve our goal of demonetization and relieve the problem of gold immobility, since the SDRs received in exchange could be used for settlement with no fear of foregoing capital gains.9

    Disadvantages: This might be a more rapid demonetization than several countries would accept. There would be no benefit from the viewpoint of financing oil imports with gold sales to Arabs (although it is not necessarily incompatible with such an arrangement).

    The only important disadvantage of option 3 would be its likely unacceptability to countries who would prefer to cling to gold for traditional reasons. But it would show our sensitivity to the immobility problem, and be a good initial bargaining position. We might, in the end, have to fall back on a fourth option:

    Option 4: Accept a European-type arrangement in which the official gold price was abolished, and official transactions at a market-related price were permitted, but with agreement that a certain portion of gold be given up to an IMF substitution facility, and that gradual further substitution of SDRs for gold would take place over a longer period of time. (One possible rule among many could be that countries should keep the nominal value of their gold holdings fixed at present levels with any increases in value coming from price increases offset by substitutions. Another variant on this proposal would have countries agree to pre-determined, gradual direct sales to the private market. Again, profits could be shared between gold holders and others.

    Advantages: This would provide adequate momentum towards gold demonetization while providing relief to gold immobility problems. It seems somewhat more compatible with gold sales to the Arabs, if this is desirable. It may be negotiable.

    Disadvantages: It is somewhat less desirable for the medium-term workings of the system than option 3.

    Conclusions

    The U.S. objectives in reducing the role of gold in the world monetary system are worthwhile, but they may be achievable without insisting on adherence to the present fixed official price of gold. Moreover, such a stand might unnecessarily create international friction. Compromise proposals exist which have good prospects for achieving our objectives for the system while meeting the principal EC requirements. We should be prepared to use these compromises in the near future.

    Tactics

    Negotiation in a broader IMF forum is likely to be a very divisive and contentious process unless based on a prior U.S.-European understanding. The Europeans, however, are not united, although working on a common substantive position. We could wait for this position to develop further or proceed now with bilateral contacts with one or more EC members. Our waiting to be confronted with the EC position puts the French in a strong position through their veto over any departure from the agreed EC line. The gold issue would be an appropriate one to pursue in bilateral contacts with the Germans and British, both of whom could probably agree to options involving more modest flex in our traditional position than the French or Italians want. But there is, of course, no guarantee that the British and/or Germans could carry the resulting compromise in Brussels. Nevertheless, working out a compromise with some of the major Europeans could reduce the prospects for a U.S.–EC standoff, while leaving a substantial intra-EC disagreement to be bridged by the Europeans.

    1. Source: National Archives, RG 56, Office of the Under Secretary of the Treasury, Files of Under Secretary Volcker, 1969–1974, Accession 56–79–15, Box 1, Gold—8/15/71–2/9/72. No classification marking. A stamped notation on the note reads: “Noted by Mr. Volcker.” Another notation, dated March 8, indicates that copies were sent to Bennett and Cross.
    2. The paper was discussed with Kissinger at a Department of State staff meeting on March 6. The summary attached to the front page of the meeting’s minutes notes that Kissinger decided: “That a small State–Treasury group, to include Volcker be assembled to refine the choices in the EB paper and report back in two weeks. The revised paper should include the options of possible unilateral EC action vis-à-vis gold prices and in relation to oil import costs as well as US responses to abort or penalize such action (EB action).” (Ibid., RG 59, Transcripts of Secretary of State Kissinger’s Staff Meetings, 1973–1977, Entry 5177, Box 2, Secretary’s Staff Meeting, March 6, 1974)
    3. Confidential.
    4. If a fixed SDR–gold price were to be maintained, and periodic free-market related adjustments in the official prices of gold were to be made, then the currency value of the world’s primary reserve assets would be tied to a price set on a volatile, unstable market. [Footnote is in the original.]
    5. As can be seen from the table at the end of this memorandum, official gold reserves are now valued at $43 billion at the $42.20 per ounce price. The free market price is almost four times the official price. [Footnote is in the original. The table is attached but not printed.]
    6. The French have stated that they do not consider the IMF Articles as binding under present circumstances (the U.S. having suspended its convertibility obligation). We consider the Articles still binding. Other countries have not yet taken a position. [Footnote is in the original.]
    7. Willy de Clercq was the Belgian Minister of Finance and Deputy Prime Minister.
    8. Under the present IMF Articles of Agreement, a generalized gold price increase (uniform par value change) would require approval of countries representing 85% of the IMF weighted voting power. Thus we have the power to block any legal change. [Footnote is in the original.]
    9. The additional SDRs might be quite acceptable since, for a time at least, they would be “backed” by IMF gold holdings. Some gold “backing” could be maintained until prejudices against paper money waned—in a manner similar to the evolution of domestic monies. [Footnote is in the original.]

    Source: History.state.gov

     

    Europa and the US are still battling about the role of gold in the worldwide monetary system

    Europa and the US are still battling about the role of gold in the worldwide monetary system